Dissertation sur antigone de sophocle

Courtesy of Special Collections, F. Olin Library, Mills College. Courtesy of the Ministero Beni e Att.

Dissertation sur antigone de sophocle

Reviewed by Colin P. Elliott, Indiana University cpe indiana. In both content and style, the book is optimistic, but with a twist: Rome's 'highly-developed, 'sophisticated', 'robust' economy was in significant part a product of a unique culture in which elites 'were constrained by very powerful, institutionalized and deeply-internalized cultural traits that compelled prosocial activity, including spending on public goods' p.

The success of the Roman economy was, therefore, due in significant part to elites' voluntary engagement in benevolent, cooperative social behaviour in order to obtain prestige and status.

UBC Theses and Dissertations

The book's methodology is situational. Arguments about the status and position of benefactors and recipients of public goods tend to be drawn from quantitative analysis of epigraphic evidence.

Deductive claims are qualitatively 'tested' by limited bodies of evidence—such as in the book's final chapter, where a generalized description of third-century A. Hoyer often gives helpful signals about which approach he is using and why it fits his argument.

The justification for combining such a variety of methodological lenses is that the book's 'Big Picture outlook' p. Hoyer's argument rests upon a set Dissertation sur antigone de sophocle epigraphic texts from the western half of the Roman Empire that relate to endowments and public buildings.

The core of Hoyer's work on these texts is found in the book's third and fourth chapters, where the epigraphic material is analyzed on multiple bases by region, by category of benefactor, by category of recipient, by principal type, etc.

Readers learn that public buildings in North Africa, for example, were often funded principally through 'private' money and that the vast majority of individual benefactors were deeply entrenched in the local or imperial political system. One of the strengths of these chapters is the way in which they show just how conflated notions of 'private' and 'public' were in the minds of those who funded, constructed and used community goods in the Roman world.

Endowments and buildings were far more than economic products—they were entrenched in a cultural framework that cannot be ignored by modern historians. Money and coinage also feature prominently in this book. In the book's second chapter, Hoyer departs from what he calls a 'statist' view of Roman money p.

Indeed, numismatic evidence over the past fifty years or so—and enough cannot be said about the contributions of thoughtfully-designed programs such as England's Portable Antiquities Scheme in harnessing the stray coin finds of metal detectorists and other amateur archaeologists—suggests that money was far more prevalent in the Roman world, including the countryside, than once thought.

Hoyer believes that money, whether in the form of cash or credit, was easily obtainable in the Roman world pp. His case rests partly upon the evidence that he surveys but also to no small degree upon implication and expectation: The ubiquity of money is a pre-requisite to his larger thesis, but also in some places a product of it.

The evidence that Hoyer discusses is meant to illuminate an unseen economic reality, as an abundance of ready money, advanced credit markets and accessible financial institutions were needed in order to produce the activity studied in the book.

Hoyer regularly insists that this evidence proves that 'there must have been active credit markets and avenues for productive investment in operation throughout the Roman world' p. Furthermore, if there was such a credit market, then Roman economic historians may need to rethink existing views on 'urban growth, industrial productivity, and trade' p.

Hoyer, therefore, shows us how culture-based impulses may create and incentivize market institutions. The Roman economy harnessed a positive feedback loop in which capital, construction, urbanization and employment worked together to reduce transaction costs and hence increase the influence and permeation of markets p.

Some scholars may object to these arguments. The 'capital' used to create public goods could just as easily be re-cast as unproductive 'consumption' of wealth generated by an agricultural surplus.

Dicton - Recherche de dictons

Construction may have generated employment, but it also sucked up surplus labor, including slave labor, which might have been used more productively. Urbanization seems to be linked with market exchange, to be sure, but it is also linked with redistribution; when cities reduced or stopped providing handouts of staples altogether, population levels fell dramatically.

Still, the provision of public goods brought returns that must also be considered. Hoyer argues that non-elite inhabitants of the ancient world—despite low wages, high prices and income inequality—benefitted through expanded access to public goods such as access to water, information, entertainment as well as communal spaces for legal, commercial and religious activities pp.

There were, nevertheless, gaps in coverage. The urban poor, for example, must have fared better than rural poor.

Dissertation qui analyse la résurgence du thème du féminisme, en comparant la pièce Antigone de Sophocle à celle d'Anouilh. Un document sur Introduction à Oedipe Roi de Sophocle - Littérature - Terminale L pour réviser gratuitement votre bac de Littérature sur digiSchool Bac L. The languagelab library successful writing intermediate dissertation cover page format template dissertation research hypothesis, essay apa format template citations essay urban and rural life forms to kill a mockingbird essay racism xps research papers in education quizlet writing a narrative essay pdf questions essay writers online uk.

In the book's fifth chapter, Hoyer argues that prosocial behaviour elevated 'well-being', a term that social scientists are still working to define. Well-being in the Roman Empire, according to Hoyer, is connected to access to public goods p.

His dissection of the ongoing debate over growth in the Roman Empire is intelligent, incisive, fair-minded and informative—any student who wishes to understand the present state of the discussion should read Hoyer's comments. Curiously, the evidence for prosocial elite activity 'falls off the cliff' around the mid third century AD p.

Honorific inscriptions in the west decrease in number, although not everywhere in the empire.

Dissertation sur antigone de sophocle

Economic instability, Hoyer argues, was nevertheless prevalent enough to undermine the prosocial culture of local elites.Un document sur Oedipe Roi de Sophocle résumé - Littérature - Terminale L pour réviser gratuitement votre bac de Littérature sur digiSchool Bac L.

“Fatorum arcana resignat,” Baltasar de Beaujoyeulx, Balet comique de la Royne, faict aux nopces de Monsieur le Duc de Joyeuse & madamoyselle de Vaudemont sa soeur. Paris: Adrien Le Roy, Robert Ballard, and Mamert Patisson, - Dictons sur dicton 1 Nos dictons du quotidien on les connaît tous, on les utilise souvent, Dico Dictons permet de redécouvrir les dictons sur le thème.

Le grand tragédien Sophocle et le dramaturge Jean Anouilh se trouvent sur le Mont Parnasse, le panthéon des poètes, la patrie de Melpomène, la Muse de la Tragédie. Invités au banquet des dieux de l'Olympe, ces deux écrivains débattent ensemble au sujet de leur pièce de théâtre qu'ils ont intitulée tous les deux «Antigone».

Dissertations Gratuites portant sur Antigone Sophocle pour les étudiants. Utilisez nos documents pour vous aider à rédiger les vôtres.

Dissertation sur antigone de sophocle

Sommaire Antigone de Jean Anouilh 2 1 Fiche signalétique d'Antigone:2 1. 1-Le contexte historique: 2 1. 2- Présentation de la pièce:4 1. 3- Structure de la.

Commentaire De Texte De Antigone De Sophocle - Dissertation - bunyboo